Surface Transportation News #180
ID 3418136 © Iofoto | Dreamstime.com

Surface Transportation Innovations Newsletter

Surface Transportation News #180

Two different visions of future mobility.

In this issue:

Unconventional Vehicles: Two Radically Different Visions

There is no question that personal transportation will undergo significant changes in coming decades. Three such changes will be the advent of affordable electric vehicles, fully autonomous vehicles, and mobility as a service (MaaS) in which people opt to rely on shared vehicles rather than individually owned vehicles. These are separate changes, which may well arrive on different time scales and with different degrees of market penetration.

Several times in recent months, various people have sent me a report that links all three together via a dramatic scenario. The report comes from RethinkX and is called “Rethinking Transportation 2020-2030,” released in May 2017. Its headline claims include the following:

  • Fully autonomous vehicles (presumably SAE Level 5) will achieve regulatory approval and be on the market in 2020.
  • By 2030, those AVs will provide 95% of all [surface] passenger miles of travel.
  • Those 95% will all be in shared vehicles (Mobility as a Service), rather than in personally owned AVs.
  • These AVs will all be electric, and will last 500,000 to 700,000 miles on their initial battery pack.

These assumptions are shared by virtually no one actually working on AVs, whether at technology companies or traditional auto companies. The past year has seen a growing number of articles explaining that full autonomy (on all kinds of roads, in all kinds of weather, etc.) is turning out to be a much harder problem than many researchers expected. Most expect gradual introduction of AV features in the next decade, with full Level 5 not being likely until at least 2035 or beyond.

As I wrote in a recent column for Public Works Financing, there is no necessary connection between electric propulsion and autonomy: neither one depends on the other. The current generation of EVs costs nearly twice as much as comparable non-EV vehicles, seriously limiting mass-market appeal. Likewise, as of now, autonomy itself requires a large array of costly sensors and very complex artificial intelligence software, Hence, RethinkX’s idea that electric AVs will be cheaper than conventional cars by 2020 looks to me like a pipe dream. In addition, the idea that the original battery pack will last 500,000 to 700,000 miles (a key to Rethink’s lower ownership cost estimate) is unproven. (The Toyota Prius battery pack has a 10-year or 150,000-mile warranty, while the Tesla Model 3 warranty is for 8 years of 100,000 miles.)

A far more realistic assessment of future mobility was released in May 2018 by S&P Global Ratings, “The Road Ahead for Autonomous Vehicles.” S&P’s analysts conclude that “mass adoption of driverless autonomous vehicles (AVs) [is] still decades away.” By contrast, they expect a faster penetration rate of electric vehicles (EVs), especially if there continue to be government “incentives” (subsidies) for those purchasing them. (S&P’s EV projections are somewhat exaggerated by including plug-in hybrids.)

S&P developed three scenarios (low/medium/high) for AV penetration, depending on a array of assumptions about technology, the price premium over conventional cars, extent of government “incentives,” growth in ride-sharing/ride-hailing (Mobility as a Service), etc. For the 2020 to 2030 period, the fraction of AVs in the total light-vehicle fleet by 2030 is projected at <1% in the low scenario, <5% in medium, and <10% in high. In Phase 2 (2030-2040), the AV fraction of the vehicle fleet would be <5% in low, <15% in medium, and <35% in high.

I find the assumptions underlying the three scenarios to be reasonable, and a number of implications for highways and travel emerge. First, even in the high (“disruptive”) scenario, only 35% of the light vehicle fleet will be AVs by 2040. So that means our roadways and highways are going to have to deal with a mixed fleet for many decades. That is far different from popular media visions of a near-term all-AV future. Second, S&P suggests that the early impacts of Level 5 AVs will be felt most by transit agencies and parking enterprises. Between 2020 and 2030, S&P expects an increase in urban traffic congestion, due partly to the continued growth of ride-hailing. (Incidentally, a new paper by Alejandro Henao and Wesley E. Marshall, “The Impact of Ride-Hailing on Vehicle Miles Traveled,” projects that “ride-hailing leads to approximately 83.5% more VMT” than would have existed had ride-hailing not emerged.) As connected AV market penetration increases beyond 2030, S&P expects “lane capacity could increase by 5% to 7% by 2030-2035 [due to] an increase in platooning.” That would partially offset the impact on highways from increased VMT due to ride-hailing and increased personal travel by those who cannot drive today (very old, very young, and disabled).

These are still early days for EVs, AVs, and MaaS. The sober analysis from S&P is a far better guide to thinking about the implications of these developments than the blue-sky vision of RethinkX.

» return to top

HOV-Lane Blues in California

HOV lane users in California are up in arms over a change in how “Clean Air Vehicles” are treated. As of January 1st, 2019, about 220,000 of them will lose their legal privilege of driving solo in the HOV lanes. Only those with newer, cleaner vehicles, will be able to get the new red decal that allows them to use those sometimes-faster HOV lanes.

I say “sometimes faster” because California HOV lanes are out of compliance with the federal standard that they must operate at 45 mph or better 90% of the time. Caltrans data for 2016 show that they met this standard only 32% of the time. There is one underlying reason: the HOV lanes are far too crowded during most peak periods to provide much of a speed improvement over the general purpose lanes. And that stems from two ill-advised policy decisions: giving out far too many Clean Air Vehicle decals and retaining the two-person minimum for all other vehicles.

The change made by the state legislature last year, making those decals available only to newer electric and CNG vehicles, will reduce the overcrowding problem, but I haven’t seen any estimates of  how much. There is no move in sight to increase the carpool requirement to HOV-3, though operators of express toll lanes (ETLs) in both Southern and Northern California have called for that change, at least for their ETLs. They want to make this change because during portions of the peak period, some ETLs in both parts of the state are closed to toll-paying vehicles altogether, once they get overloaded with HOV-2s and currently-permitted Clean Air Vehicles. And that is an absurd outcome.

As I have written here previously, the transportation plans in both the San Francisco Bay Area and the greater Los Angeles metro area include large-scale networks of express toll lanes. Near-real-time variable pricing is the best (and only) way we know of to keep such lanes free-flowing during times of very high demand. But that pricing can only perform this seeming miracle if most or nearly all the vehicles desiring to use the ETLs actually have to pay the variable price to do so. Exempting large numbers of vehicles from paying, so as to promote other policy goals (carpooling/fam-pooling and cleaner air), destroys the power of pricing to control traffic flow. If current policies remain in effect as the planned ETL networks are built, there is a very high risk that they will not work.

Other metro areas are going from HOV-2 to HOV-3 as they move into implementing ETLs. And a small but growing number are dispensing with HOV exemptions altogether, on the grounds of increased pricing power and the ability of genuine car-poolers to split the charge, thereby still being better off by using the priced lanes. Let’s hope California policy-makers can figure this out before they build ETL networks that fail to provide meaningful congestion relief.

» return to top

New Commuting Data from Census ACS Data

The American Community Survey data on vehicle ownership and commuting mode choice were released last month by the U.S. Census Bureau. The headline finding was that the fraction of those working mostly at home nationwide—5.2%—now exceeds the national average for those commuting by transit—5.0%. This has been true of a growing number of medium and large metro areas for quite a few years, but this is the first time it’s been reported on a national average basis.

Comparing commuting modes over time reveals considerable stability in most of the mode shares. Consider the changes between 2005 and the new 2017 numbers:

 

Mode
2005
2017
Drove alone 77.0% 76.4%
Carpooled 10.7%   8.9%
Public transit   4.7%   5.0%
Walked   2.5%   2.7%
Biked   0.4%   0.5%
Other   1.2%   1.3%
Worked at home   3.6%   5.2%

The “other” category includes taxi and ride-hail companies, and although the latter have displaced a lot of taxi service, the national average for that whole category is still not much more than 1%.

The largest group of people now in the active workforce is the Millennial generation. They were supposed to be giving up car ownership and getting around by walking, biking, transit, and ride-hailing. But it’s difficult to see much evidence of those alleged trends in the overall statistics (though figures for individual cities may show different patterns).

The other fascinating feature in the new ACS data is the stability in vehicle ownership, albeit with a slight rise in the fraction of multi-vehicle households and a resumption in the trend (post-recession) of an ever-smaller number of zero-car households (from a high of 9.3% in 2012 to 8.6% in 2017. Three-vehicle households have increased from 19.8% in 2005 to 21.5% in 2017, with two-vehicle households decreasing slightly from 38.2% in 2005 to 37.1% in 2017. So far, at least, the United States is still a car-owning society.

» return to top

INRIX Data Show Some Progress on U.S. Congestion

Big-data firm INRIX last month released its 2017 Global Traffic Scorecard. It reports data on the extent of traffic congestion in 1,360 metro areas worldwide. Of the world’s 10 most-congested metro areas, five are in the United States. The non-U.S. members of that elite group are Moscow (2nd most-congested), Sao Paulo (4th), Bogota (6th), London (7th), and Paris (10th).

When I reviewed the 13 U.S. metro areas that made the INRIX top 45 most-congested, some very interesting patterns emerged. Here is my summary of the data.

Metro Area 2017 rank 2016 rank Change Hrs./motorist congested % of peak congested Pricing extent
Los Angeles 1 1 0 102/year 21% Low
New York 3 3 0 91 30% Low
San Francisco 5 4 -1 79 21% Med.
Atlanta 10 9 -1 70 17% Med.
Miami 14 11 -3 64 13% High
Washington 18 15 -3 63 20% Med.
Boston 19 18 -1 60 23% Low
Chicago 22 19 -3 57 17% Med.
Seattle 26 23 -3 55 22% Low
Dallas 28 16 -12 54 11% High
Houston 37 28 -9 50 13% High
Portland 40 40 0 50 21% None
San Diego 45 47 +2 48 19% Med.

The extent of pricing is my subjective assessment of the fraction of limited-access facilities that are either toll roads or variably priced managed lanes. When I used the percentage of peak period that is congested, I found that the average for those in metro areas rated high on pricing was 12.3%; for those rated medium, the average was 18.8%; and for those rated low (or none), the average was 23.4%.

The other point that leaps out of the table is the change in rank of Dallas and Houston, both of which moved significantly lower in the league table of most-congested metro areas. Both have a growing fraction of their expressways that are tollways, and both have expanding networks of variably priced managed lanes. Also striking is that Portland, with just one-third the population of Dallas, has nearly the same average congested hours per commuter and has nearly double the percentage of peak period hours that are congested. Perhaps this explains why Portland is on the verge of a decision to implement pricing on several of its freeways.

» return to top

Could Florida’s Brightline Go Nationwide?

Since June, there has been a flurry of interest in Brightline, the privately financed higher-speed passenger railroad, Phase 1 of which is now in service between Miami, Fort Lauderdale and West Palm Beach, and which has issued tax-exempt private activity bonds (PABs) to start building Phase 2, from West Palm Beach to Orlando. Recent media coverage has included the following:

  • An article in Florida Trend quoting Brightline as looking nationwide for other corridors that are “too far to drive, too short to fly,” citing prospects like Atlanta-Charlotte, Chicago-St. Louis, and Dallas-Houston (May 14th).
  • An unsolicited proposal from Brightline to Florida DOT to build a Phase 3, from Orlando to Tampa. Florida Gov. Rick Scott promised an RFP that would permit Brightline and others to submit competing proposals (June 22nd).
  • Announcement that Brightline has acquired Xpress West, a startup that tried to finance a $7 billion high-speed train between Victorville, CA and Las Vegas, but was turned down for about $5 billion worth of federal RRIF loans (Sept. 18th).
  • A summary of these developments in The Economist, which suggested that Brightline might have trouble getting permission to operate on existing freight railroads, a problem that did not arise in Florida (Sept. 22nd).

I’ve been generally supportive of Brightline, partly because it has approached passenger rail with fresh thinking, and especially because it has relied entirely on private financing. (Those PABs are revenue bonds, bought by sophisticated investors; taxpayers are not at risk.) But these proposed expansions raise the question of whether the company can replicate the success factors that have made its initial Florida operation a plausible business. Besides choosing corridors of the right length linking metro areas with large populations, other success factors include the following:

  • Selecting higher-speed, achievable via diesel propulsion, rather than more-costly electric propulsion and the higher track costs and operating costs of 200 mph service, as in Japan and Europe;
  • Relying largely on existing freight rail right of way, modified to ensure compatibility between short 75-100 mph passenger trains and long, slow freight trains that are most railroads’ bread and butter;
  • Avoiding stations and stops at small cities along the way, to reduce trip times and infrastructure costs;
  • Not having to build major new bridges or tunnels; and,
  • Exploiting the synergy between high-volume passenger stations and adjacent real-estate land value.

One clue to a possible evolution in Brightline’s model has emerged in discussions of the Tampa-Orlando line and the Xpress West project. In both cases, the company is talking about leasing right of way along existing Interstate highways: I-4 in Florida and I-15 in California. As I pointed out to the Los Angeles Times reporter who interviewed me about the Xpress West acquisition, the downside of this for future mobility is the extent to which adding a rail line precludes needed future expansion of those Interstates, whether for growing truck traffic or increased personal travel. What economists call the “opportunity cost” of giving up scarce highway right of way needs to be taken into account by DOTs asked to sign long-term rail leases.

To its credit, in the Xpress West corridor Brightline is talking about diesel propulsion and about not building costly tunnels beneath the mountains between Victorville and Las Vegas. Yet even at half the estimated $7 billion cost of the original group’s plan, its ridership projections were hard to believe. There is loads of inexpensive airline service to Las Vegas from the five airports conveniently located around the greater LA area. And as for driving, the worst part of the trip is from people’s origin in the LA metro area to about as far as Victorville. After that, I-15 is a relatively uncongested straight shot to Las Vegas.

There are still railroad lines between Los Angeles itself and Las Vegas; Amtrak ran the Desert Wind passenger train on them until ending the service in 1997. So there is an alternative to serving Vegas from Victorville and using the limited right of way along I-15. Perhaps once Brightline does serious traffic and revenue studies, it will consider that alternative.

» return to top

Taking a Careful Look at “Vision Zero”
By Baruch Feigenbaum

As economic activity and vehicle miles traveled increase in U.S. metro areas, many central cities are facing an increase in traffic-related accidents and fatalities. The unfortunate knee-jerk reaction is for politicians to accept nothing less than zero injuries or fatalities total. While aiming for zero incidents is a laudable goal for every city to target, creating strict anti-mobility policies to reach that goal can jeopardize economic activity. Further, achieving zero incidents requires modifying behaviors that policy makers may not have the power to change.

The template for the no injuries and fatalities movement is Vision Zero. Vision Zero originated in Sweden in the late 1990s when the Swedish parliament accepted it as the official road policy. Sweden has one of the lowest annual road fatality rates at 3 per 100,000 people. Further, as road fatalities have been increasing in the United States, they have been falling in Sweden.

Vision Zero is different from traditional safety plans because its central premise accepts that humans will make mistakes. Instead of trying to change human behavior so that drivers actually follow road safety laws, Vision Zero creates a system where humans are protected if they make mistakes. Since the majority of fatalities in most central cities are pedestrians and cyclists, the number-one priority of Vision Zero activists is significantly reducing automobile speeds. Speed is a major contributing factor in traffic fatalities. Striking a pedestrian at 31 mph results in a fatality 80% of the time, but striking a pedestrian at 19 mph results in a fatality less than 10% of the time.

Vision Zero sets the speed limits based on the type of infrastructure. This details the different environments.

Vision Zero Maximum Travel Speeds
Types of Infrastructure and Traffic Maximum Travel Speed (mph)
Locations with possible conflicts between pedestrians and cars 19
Intersections with possible side impacts between cars 31
Roads with possible frontal impacts between cars 43
Roads with no possibility of a side impact or frontal impact 62

Safety is an important aspect of any transportation system. There are certainly circumstances where transportation officials don’t weigh safety as much as they should. For example, Virginia’s otherwise laudable Smart Scale program for transportation project selection weights safety as low as 5%, depending on the metro area.

However, there are many problems with Sweden’s Vision Zero initiative. For one thing, it lacks any kind of cost-benefit analysis. It implicitly assumes that one life has an infinite monetary value. However, that’s not how sound public policy is made. While it may sound callous, insurance companies assign monetary values to customers; this is how they determine how much money to pay after fatal events. Health agencies calculate the cost of pandemics by assigning monetary values. The US DOT and other federal agencies use standard “value of a life saved” figures in making regulations. Since resources are always limited, it’s irrational to ignore costs. Further, achieving the last 10% of a quantitative goal nearly always costs far more than achieving the first 90%. In other words, reducing deaths by 90% would be more realistic than spending ever-more money trying to eliminate all such deaths

One of the creators of Vision Zero, Matts-Ake Belin, noted that the hardest part of implementing Vision Zero in Sweden was political economists influenced by the “utilitarian mindset.” Yet that underlying principle is how the US DOT and other agencies make policy. Yes, some folks place a higher value on cost-benefit analysis than others. But everybody bases at least some of their decision-making on cost-benefit analysis. Think of your last trip to the supermarket. There may have been one or two products that you intended to purchase. But after seeing bananas priced at $5.00 per pound, you decided to go to a different supermarket or buy apples instead. Yet in Vision Zero, no price—not $100,000 per pound or $100,000,000 per pound—would cause you to reconsider. That way of thinking is just bananas.

Also unsettling is Vision Zero’s underlying paternalistic approach. All transportation system users should be paying attention to where they are going. By creating a forgiving environment, Vision Zero encourages poor behaviors because there are limited consequences. Irresponsible behaviors such as texting, driving while drowsy, and lack of situational awareness have increased in some cities after Vision Zero implementation.

The most important question is whether Vision Zero works, and the answer is no. Zero traffic-related deaths have not occurred in any major city in the world since the program began. In part that’s because the goal is unrealistic, which is what the political economists afflicted with the “utilitarian mindset” told the Swedish government more than 20 years ago.

There are no peer-reviewed articles showing that Vision Zero works. Pedestrian deaths have declined in New York City, a Vision Zero pioneer. However, deaths of bicyclists, motorcyclists and drivers rose. After spending $27 million, Los Angeles deaths declined only 6% between 2016 and 2017, not the 20% experts expected.

Further, U.S. cities are not implementing Vision Zero as originally defined. For example, Washington DC is enacting $1,000 fines for speeding, supposedly to improve safety. Yet that’s not how Sweden designed Vision Zero. Sweden installed traffic cameras as a deterrent. The idea was that over time people would change their behavior. Drivers did not receive harsh traffic fines, just warnings.

Therefore, some are wondering if Vision Zero is about safety or more of an excuse to make driving more difficult (and enrich city coffers in the bargain). Some of the cities implementing the policy have set unrealistic goals for reducing single-occupant driving. Los Angeles wants to reduce the share of single-occupant vehicles to less than 50%. Washington DC has set a goal of 25%. Neither of these is at all realistic. But if the goal is to punish drivers, Vision Zero could be a useful tool.

Vision Zero is a failed policy from a paternalistic government that takes millions of dollars to implement and never reaches its goal of zero deaths, in part because its goal is completely unrealistic. But Vision Zero does make life harder for commuters and those delivering freight. Yet this is the policy that many U.S. cities want to implement.

» return to top

Upcoming Transportation Events

Note: We don’t have the time or space to list all transportation events that might be of interest to readers of this newsletter. Listed here are events at which a Reason Foundation transportation researcher is speaking or moderating.

ITS Summit 5C Event, Oct. 7-10, 2018, Jacksonville, FL, Hyatt Regency Jacksonville (Baruch Feigenbaum speaking). Details at: http://www.its5Csummit.com.

Rethinking America’s Highways: A Book Talk with Robert Poole, October 10th, University of Texas at Arlington, Rio Grande Ballroom B (Robert Poole speaking). Details at: https://rethinkingamericashighways.eventbrite.com

IBTTA Annual Meeting, Oct. 14-16, 2018, Baltimore, MD, Baltimore Marriott Waterfront (Robert Poole speaking). Details at: https://www.ibtta.org/events/86th-annual-meeting-exhibition.

Rethinking America’s Highways, Oct. 31, 2018, USC Urban Growth Seminar, University of Southern California (Robert Poole speaking). Details at: https://goo.gl/forms/uupo3LZziRKu97Hn2

Rethinking America’s Highways, Nov. 1, 2018, UC-Irvine, Irvine, CA (Robert Poole speaking). Details to come.

Rethinking America’s Highways, Nov. 1, 2018, Chapman University, Orange, CA (Robert Poole speaking). Details to come.

» return to top

News Notes

New Toll Road Approved in Miami. Thanks in part to strong support from Miami-Dade County Mayor Carlos Gimenez, the County Commission voted Sept. 27th to approve a $1 billion extension of the tolled Dolphin Expressway. Called the Kendall Parkway, the 13-mile route would provide congestion relief to many of the 600,000 people who live in the southwestern suburbs of Miami-Dade County. It will expand the network of toll roads operated by the Miami-Dade Expressway Authority, and will be financed by toll revenue bonds.

Clear Thinking on Mobility as a Service. Analyst Blair Schlecter last year produced a three-part series on autonomous vehicles, Part 1 of which is on Mobility as a Service. Though seeing benefits in MaaS, he notes that “the fact that AVs can pick up passengers all day without a driver does not in itself present a compelling reason for a person to shift from ownership to sharing. Rather, a number of other considerations, including convenience, safety, speed, and overall cost likely will shape consumer decisions about whether to own or share.” The title of the first article is “Case Studies in Autonomous Vehicles, Part 1: Shared Use Vehicles and the Challenges of Multiple, Intermediate Stops.” Part 2 continues these thoughts, dealing with passengers with non-routine needs. All three are on the NewGeography.com website and are well worth reading.

Indiana Finance Authority Approves Truck Toll Increase. On Sept. 20th, the board of the Indiana Finance Authority, which oversees the long-term P3 lease of the Indiana Toll Road, approved ITR’s proposed 35% increase in tolls on large trucks, bringing those toll rates into the same range as on other tolled Interstates in the Midwest. The negotiated deal will result in $1 billion paid to the state over three years for investment in transportation infrastructure, in particular the completion of (non-tolled) I-69.

New Concern for Connected Vehicles: Hacking and Spoofing. Two University of Michigan researchers, Qi Alfred Chen and Z. Morley Mao, have found that current connected-vehicle algorithms are subject to being interfered with. They studied the Intelligent Traffic Signal System that is being installed in New York City and Tampa and found that the algorithms “are relatively easy to trick,” making it possible for malicious hackers to bring about massive traffic jams. See the summary article in The Conversation, “Connected Cars Can Lie, Posing a New Threat to Smart Cities.”

New Provider for HELP Trucking System. The PrePass system that enables qualified trucks to bypass weigh stations and pay tolls electronically has a new operating company. Infrastructure investment firm Alinda Capital Partners has acquired HELP’s contractor, CVO Holding Company. HELP CEO Karen Rasmussen said “The HELP Board viewed Alinda’s partnership proposal as an intriguing next step to providing even greater innovation and continuous improvements to customer service.”

Major P3 Traffic Tunnel Approved in Chile. The $940 million Autopista Americo Vespucio Oriente tunnel has received environmental approvals to begin construction. The 9.1 km tunnel is the northern segment of 14.5 km worth of tunnels to close a missing link on the tolled ring road around capital city Santiago. The team of Spain’s Sacyr and Australia’s IFM Investors has a 45-year toll concession for this project. The double-deck tunnel will have three lanes on each level. Above, at ground level, there will be bus, bicycle, and pedestrian lanes.

Debate Over Paying for Hartford Mega-Tunnel. In a public hearing last month, officials from Washington State cautioned Hartford, CT leaders not to expect massive federal funding for the proposed project. Former WashDOT Secretary Paula Hammond noted that federal funds paid for only 30% of Seattle’s new $3.3 billion double-deck tunnel. But Rep. John Larson (D, CT) held out hope for major federal funding of the proposed 2-mile Hartford tunnel, aimed (like Seattle’s) at replacing an aging viaduct on portions of I-84 and I-91 in Hartford. Not mentioned in news reports on the meeting was the potential of toll financing and variable pricing.

 “Why Can’t New York Control Its Infrastructure Costs?” That’s the title of a devastating article by Connor Harris in the Summer 2018 issue of the Manhattan Institute’s magazine, City Journal. The article builds on recent investigative articles in the New York Times documenting that major cities overseas, including London, Seoul, and Tokyo, are building new subway tunnels at a small fraction of the cost per mile of New York City projects. The article indicts a failed “New York transportation establishment” that if not thoroughly reformed, will replicate this irresponsible cost performance on the much-needed Gateway tunnels project.

First Phase of New I-11 Opens in Nevada. In August, Nevada officials and FHWA Deputy Administrator Brandye Hendrickson took part in the grand opening of the first 15 miles of Interstate 11, which is planned to link Las Vegas with Phoenix—two of the largest U.S. metro areas without a direct Interstate connection.

China-Type Highways for India? LinkedIn recently carried a thoughtful article by investor Harsh Gupta titled “India Needs China’s Expressways.” While not endorsing the questionable Chinese Belt & Road effort, Gupta compared the huge network of limited-access highways that have been implemented in China over the past two decades with the still rather pathetic state of major highways in India. He suggests using Google Maps to compare travel times between pairs of Chinese cities and pairs of Indian cities to illustrate the impact of the latter country’s primitive highways.

$150 Million Cline Avenue Bridge Aims for 2020 Opening. The privately owned toll bridge across the Indiana Harbor and Ship Canal in East Chicago, IN is well along in construction. Developer/operator United Bridge Partners told a forum in Gary, IN last month that the company is producing pre-cast bridge segments at the pace of three per day, with a scheduled opening date early in 2020. The bridge replaces an obsolete bridge that was shut down in 2009. The initial span will have one lane each way, but plans call for twinning that span in future years when traffic warrants doing so.

First P3 Concession in Michigan Moving Forward. Michigan DOT has announced the team of Aecom and John Laing as the preferred bidder for a $575 million project to upgrade I-75 in the Detroit metro area. Financial close is expected by the end of the year. The 30-year DBFOM concession will use availability payments to compensate the concession company over the life of the agreement. The five-mile project is part of an 18-mile project to modernize that stretch of I-75.

Poole Capitol Hill Book Presentation Available Online. On Sept. 7th, your editor was the main speaker at a well-attended Capitol Hill briefing in Washington, DC organized and hosted by the Cato Institute. The focus was the new book, Rethinking America’s Highways. Thoughtful commentary was provided by Prof. Jonathan Gifford of George Mason University, and Cato’s Chris Edwards served as moderator. Cato posted a video of the session at https://www.cato.org/events/rethinking-americas-highways.

“Does More Federal Highway Spending Mean More Total Highway Spending?”
That’s the question asked and answered by Jeff Davis, editor of Eno Transportation Weekly on Sept. 4th. Davis reviews studies by the Congressional Budget Office and by various academic researchers over the past 15 years. Davis’s overall conclusion might be summed up as, “often it does not.” The most recent evidence is a CBO working paper released at the beginning of September, concluding that “Researchers have found evidence that state and local governments reduce spending on highways from their own funds as federal grants increase.” The CBO paper is “Fiscal Substitution of Investment for Highway Infrastructure,” and is on the CBO website: https://www.cbo.gov/publication/54371.

Bloomberg Calls for Highway Charging Stations—But Ignores Interstate Rest Areas. In an otherwise thoughtful op-ed published on Sept. 16th, Michael Bloomberg referred to the Interstate highway system as a great achievement that risks becoming an “aging relic” due to not keeping up with changing technology. What’s needed, he wrote, is charging stations for electric vehicles. But the most customer-friendly location for those facilities is at the “rest areas” of long-distance Interstates. Bloomberg had a perfect opportunity to call for enabling this by urging repeal of the 1956 federal ban on “commercial” services at Interstate rest areas. Nobody expects electricity to be given away at charging stations, so by definition they are “commercial.” It’s high time this policy relic from 1956 was given the axe.

Arlington, TX Relies on Private-Sector Transit. After losing money on a conventional bus line, suburban Arlington (home of a University of Texas campus as well as a Six Flags amusement park) has set forth a new transit vision. It will be based on contracting with private operators of new-technology vehicles. In August, the city announced a contract with Drive.ai to operate free shuttles serving major destinations. Called Via, the service uses six-passenger vans providing on-demand, nearly door-to-door service. The vehicles are intended to be autonomous, but will initially have a safety driver behind the wheel. Once the autonomous technology has been proven and the vans can operate without the driver, the plan is to offer the service at $3 per ride.

Ballot Measure to Repeal California High-Speed Rail. The sponsors of a measure on the November 2018 ballot that would repeal a recent increase in highway fuel taxes announced late last month that they were filing a new measure, for the 2020 ballot. It would halt construction of the HSR project and require any unspent funds not needed to pay off existing rail bonds to be re-directed to other transportation investment. The measure would also require all gasoline and diesel tax revenue to be spent entirely on roads and highways. Proponents will have to collect at least 500,000 signatures to qualify for the ballot. Recent public opinion polls show declining support for the HSR project in most of the state, apart from the San Francisco Bay Area.

Alternative Project Delivery Highlighted by TRB Publication. The July-August issue of the Transportation Research Board’s magazine, TR News, is focused on alternatives to the conventional design-bid-build method of project procurement. Articles include case studies of how alternatives have been introduced in Colorado and Georgia, best practices in design-build, and risk-sharing in design-build-finance-operate-maintain (DBFOM) procurement.

New AASHTO Executive Director. Congratulations to Jim Tymon, who was appointed the new executive director of the American Association of State Highway and Transportation Officials. Tymon, who has recently been AASHTO’s chief operating officer, was previously staff director of the House Highways & Transit Subcommittee and senior advisor to Rep. Bill Shuster (R, PA), chairman of the parent Transportation & Infrastructure Committee.

NCHRP Reports on Impact of CVs and AVs on Transportation Agencies. The National Cooperative Highway Research Program has released an array of reports under NCHRP Project 20-102, with additional reports to come in the fourth quarter of 2018. Topics include policy and planning for state and local agencies, transit-specific implications, truck freight challenges, and AV legal issues. Details are available at http://bit.ly/2y8gEm4 or by emailing Ray Derr (rderr@nas.edu).

Funding Transportation via Land Value Recycling. NCHRP has released a guidebook containing a wealth of information on the potential and previous use of the increases in land value brought about by new transportation infrastructure to help pay for that infrastructure. A PDF of the guidebook is available at http://nap.edu/25110.

Correction to Last Issue. Joe Milazzo of the Regional Transportation Alliance in North Carolina pointed out that the North Carolina Quickpass toll transponder is interoperable with E-ZPass as well as the statewide PeachPass and SunPass systems in Georgia and Florida.

» return to top

Quotable Quotes

“[C]ities should recognize that traffic and pollution are different problems. One reason why London’s congestion charge is losing its potency is because the city offers a number of exemptions for greener vehicles. Since both low-emission cars and gas-guzzlers contribute to traffic, both should pay congestion charges. Regulating to reduce emissions—or imposing a separate charge on high-emission vehicles, as London plans to do next year—is the better way to tackle pollution.”
—Editorial, “Rules of the Road,” The Economist, August 25, 2018

“Operating [an AV shuttle] on public streets in mixed traffic [in Las Vegas] is no small accomplishment—even if it does have an ‘ambassador’ on board. All systems will/do have them in the beginning. The record so far is impressive. As more experience is gained, it will be able to scale to provide mobility to the many that don’t need an attendant but need to be able to get from where they are to where they are going when they want to go, affordably. Wouldn’t that be something. A transit system that caters to the demand of its customers, rather than demanding that the rider is forced to adhere to the system’s fixed routes (of which there are few) at fixed times (which are certainly not 24/7 and widely separated). Combined, [those attributes mean] the scheduled service actually ends up serving so very few.”
—Alain Kornhauser, “U.S. Cities Building on Las Vegas Success with Autonomous Buses,” Smart Driving Cars, Sept. 22, 2018

“Traffic [congestion] is a drain on our economy and our quality of life. But it doesn’t have to be this way. . . . With smarter tolling, some drivers would pay less with off-peak tolls. But the biggest beneficiaries would be the drivers with the least flexibility. If it is important for you to be on the road at the busiest times, then you want that road to be as free from other cars as possible. By reducing peak-hour traffic, smarter tolling provides those without flexibility what they need and deserve: a better, faster, more-reliable commute.”
—Chris Dempsey, “Should Massachusetts Discount Road and Bridge Tolls During Off-Peak Hours?” Boston Globe, Sept 13, 2018

“Millennials are following in the footsteps of previous generations by locating on the periphery of major metropolitan areas and sunbelt cities, most of which are simply agglomerations of suburbs. Over the last year, according to the Census, the ranks of renters decreased while home ownership increased 1.8 million. A recent National Homebuilders Association report shows that more than two in three Millennials, including most of those living in cities, would prefer a house in the suburbs, findings confirmed as well by the Conference Board and Nielsen.”
—Joel Kotkin, “California Must Stop Trying to Stomp Out Suburbia,” NewGeography.com, Sept. 14, 2018

“Ask someone about the industry’s adoption of public-private partnerships (P3s), and they may describe it as slow. But is it really? Or is it the normal progression of a new delivery method? Design-build delivery took 30 years to go mainstream, and yet some states still have not embraced it. Changing how the surface transportation industry has delivered projects for the past 100 years takes time. The practice of leveraging private-sector developers to finance, [build], operate, and maintain large transportation projects is only 15 years old. The fact that the U.S. sees an average of two large transactions per year is the normal course of adoption. Having said that, there are numerous indicators that the pipeline is primed for an increased flow of deals in our country.”
—Brad Guilmino, “Deals Show Promise, Potential, as More DOTs Use Them,” RoadsBridges.com, September 6, 2018

“The cool way to get to your co-working space is on a shared, dockless, electric scooter. You see them littering the streets of cities near you. Companies like Lime, Bird, and Ofo have been raising tons of money at huge valuations. Even Lyft is scootering. Meanwhile, losses mount. The China Economic Review says Ofo, known for its bike-sharing service, may be losing $25 million a week. In round numbers, scooters cost around $400. In Santa Monica, CA, Bird riders pay $1 a ride plus 15 cents a minute, averaging $3 a ride. Scooters are used five or six times a day. Generating $15 a day means the scooter pays for itself in under two months. The spreadsheets are flashing green! But, and there’s always a but, expenses are still murky. You pay someone to charge the scooters. And cities are wising up and piling on fees. Portland, OR is adding all kinds of surcharges. Oops. Usage numbers are suspect, as scooters are still new and fun. Lime and Bird report more than 10 million rides each. But I’d guess churn is huge. No one knows how long scooters will last before they end up in rivers or garbage dumps like China’s bike graveyards. Fads are never great investments.”
—Andy Kessler, “The Company Implosion Pageant,” The Wall Street Journal, Sept. 24, 2018

» return to top